Politiek en historie. Opstellen over Nederlandse politiek en vergelijkende politieke wetenschap
(2011)–Hans Daalder– Auteursrechtelijk beschermd
[pagina 271]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Capitalism, colonialism and the underdeveloped areas
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 272]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
chance to become equal members of a cosmopolitan universe? Would not free trade, allowing the unfettered working of the principle of comparative costs, most quickly increase the wealth of all nations?Ga naar eind3 Within half a century this image drastically changed. A resurgent protectionism destroyed the ideal picture of a world in which individuals rather than states would be the basic units of economic exchange. For a time some lip-service was still paid to the ultimate ideal. Protection, so it was argued, was only a temporary expedient, necessary while infant industries were being nursed to maturity. But once (re-)introduced, protection itself created strong vested interests, powerful enough to block any attempt at restoring free trade. In addition, the danger to which cheap Russian and American grain exposed the agricultural world in the latter part of the 19th century, rallied another powerful sector of the national communities in favour of protectionism. The very principle of comparative costs, working in a world market was challenged by those who, like Germany's Nationaloekonomen, argued that socially balanced economies within the existing state boundaries were preferable to the theoretical gains of international specialization. The rapid rise of Germany and the usa as powerful industrial competitors, in turn, kindled somewhat similar doctrines in the bastion of free trade, Britain itself. Influential publicists came to argue in favour of a Greater Britain, linked to the Mother Country by a programme of what later ideologues were to call ‘Imperial Free Trade’. Protection of the home market and safeguarding colonial markets, so ran their exhortations, were necessary if Britain were to retain its prosperity and political predominance. The argument met with small favour from the Little Englanders. True to the tradition of the classical economists, anti-colonialists found as little economic profit in neo-Mercantilism as their forefathers had found in Mercantilism. Yet, the economic argument stuck. Once the problem of colonial expansion came to be argued in economic terms, protagonists and adversaries alike came to attribute causal significance to economic interests. If the first pointed to the profits which were to be reaped by the entire nation, the latter attempted to show that small profiteering groups tried to make the nation bleed for selfish interests. By the end of the 19th century these diverse currents crystallized into a full-scale theory of imperialism which linked colonial conquest to the machinations of capitalism. Originally a term of abuse flung at French immorality,Ga naar eind4 the word had already been converted into a domestic invective by British opponents of Disraeli's expansionist policies. As so often occurs, the term was upgraded by those denounced. Protagonists of British expansion proudly took up the label Imperialist, while the anti-Imperialists continued to castigate the word, as they castigated the programme. Until the end of the century, however, colonial conflicts continued to be regarded as incidents in which | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 273]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
local interests and distant European Chancelleries had a greater stake than nations. The Jameson raid and the Boer War itself changed all this. Britain, so it seemed, stepped down publicly from its self-chosen pedestal of high morality into the dirty world of Realpolitiker, out for prestige and profit at the bidding of the capitalists of the South African Rand. Did not the South African War show that capitalist search for profit, colonial domination and international aggressiveness were one? The image of the Pax Britannica stood condemned as a pure ideology. In 1900, a Congress of the Socialist International, meeting in Paris, passed a resolution affirming that the development of capitalism led inexorably to colonial expansion, and hence to intergovernmental conflicts, imperialism, chauvinism, militarism, cruelty and exploitation of subject races. Two years later, J.A. Hobson published his Imperialism: A Study, which quickly became a classic document in the English language. The book attempted to show how the underconsumptionist tendencies of capitalism, and the profiteering proclivities of individual capitalists, were the cause of the New Imperialism. In the next decades similar doctrines were elaborated, in greater detail and with more analytical rigour, by a number of Marxist authors in Germany and Austria, of whom Rudolf Hilferding, Otto Bauer, and Rosa Luxemburg were the most prominent. They were finally presented to the layman in loaded phrases by Lenin in his Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism (Petrograd, 1917, published in other European languages in 1920). The theories which attributed colonialism to capitalism were formed to a considerable extent post factum. Colonial conquest had been practically completed, before the theories were formulated. This theoretical (as well as emotional) lag has since persisted. Political developments and academic criticism by economists and historians may have eroded the academic respectability of Marxist theories. They may have failed as an explanation of past history. But their emotional impact has continued to be such that they had, and continue to have, substantial influence on the history of the relations between the West, the Communist block, and the newly emerging nations. This circumstance makes for a natural division of this chapter into two parts. In the first section, attention is paid to some intellectual flaws and historical errors inherent in histories which seek to explain the new colonialism of the late 19th and early 20th century by an exclusive reference to capitalism and capitalists. This is necessary, on the one hand, to obtain a better perspective of the basically political phenomenon of Imperialism, and, on the other, to reveal certain misunderstandings about the nature of the economic relationships which existed over the past century between the developed Western nations and the still underdeveloped territories in Asia, Africa and Latin America. Then, in the second section, a short summary is given of the impact which such theories have had on the political outlook of | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 274]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
the historical actors in the West, the Communist world, and the developing areas. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Section I
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
I The expansion of capitalism and the existence of non-capitalist economiesThe most detailed formulation of the theory that capitalism could only continue to expand because non-capitalist territories and social groups provided it with markets, was the theory of Rosa Luxemburg.Ga naar eind5 She laid down her views particularly in two publications: Die Akkumulation des Kapitals (1913, English edition by Joan Robinson, 1951), followed by a polemical pamphlet, Die Akkumulation des Kapitals, oder Was die Epigonen aus der Marxschen Theorie gemacht haben: Eine Antikritik (1915).Ga naar eind6 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 275]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The fundamental theoretical question posed by Rosa Luxemburg was: how could capitalism continue to expand, at a time when workers lacked adequate purchasing power, and capitalists limited their consumption of surplus value because of their ever-present drive for further accumulation of capital? Marx himself had wrestled with this question. At the end of Volume ii of Capital, he had attempted a solution by constructing an arithmetical scheme of capital accumulation. This scheme rested on certain specific assumptions, however, which had been rejected as unrealistic by Marx himself in other parts of his writing. Marx and his disciples had therefore continued to look for a solution for the prima facie absence of effective demand in capitalism. They had mentioned gold, credit, additional labourers employed in capital formation, a growing population, or foreign trade as possible explanations of the continued expansion of the system. But so far, all these attempts to solve the dilemma within the general framework of the Marxist scheme had not been very satisfactory. After reviewing these suggestions, Rosa Luxemburg rejected them all. She concluded that Marx's assumption of a closed economy, which consisted of capitalists and labourers only, was in itself unrealistic and untenable. Capitalism, she stated, could not exist as a self-contained system. It could only continue to grow by being parasitical on non-capitalist economies. Only if non-capitalist producers (like farmers at home or producers in virgin areas overseas who had not yet been brought within the ambit of capitalist production) continued to buy otherwise unsaleable capitalist products, could capitalism develop. Consequently, once the entire world were drawn fully into the system of capitalist production, capitalism was bound to succumb to its inner contradictions. ‘Imperialism’, to Rosa Luxemburg, was therefore ‘just as much a historical method to prolong the life of Capital, as the most certain means by which it will be set a definite end in the shortest possible timespan’.Ga naar eind7 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Theoretical flaws in the argumentTheoretically, Rosa Luxemburg's theory suffered from three basic defects: 1) she underestimated the extent to which investment could provide a continuous effective demand without increasing at the same time the output of consumer goods in search of effective buyers; 2) like other Marxist writers, she also underestimated the general increase of consumer demand which accompanied the rise of national income in European countries; and, finally, 3) even if the tenability of her argument were granted quod non, the solution she offered that non-capitalist buyers could provide the effective demand which was supposedly lacking in a closed capitalist system was little but an escape from the problem she herself proposed to elucidate. 1. The relation between investment and consumption. - Rosa Luxem- | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 276]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
burg had indignantly rejected Say's Law, which held that each new product which is brought to market creates its own demand. Investment, she argued, could not but increase the eventual production of consumer goods. As these goods would find no buyers, investments themselves would necessarily come to a stop. In putting this, she disagreed with certain passages in Marx's own writings; and she disagreed emphatically with the theories of the Russian Legal Marxist, Tugan Baranowsky.Ga naar eind8 Reviewing Marx' writings, Tugan Baranowsky had concluded that in a closed capitalist system no difficulties need arise provided capitalists were to accumulate indefinitely, in one continuous process of investment for investment's sake. He had granted that crises might and did arise in the process, when partial overproduction of certain investment goods might lead to temporary dislocations. But he had not hesitated to state bluntly that, as long as investments were to continue unabated, consumer demand could, theoretically, even actually decrease without causing an underconsumptionist crisis. Rosa Luxemburg had branded this theory a picture of a ‘tireless merry-go-round turning in a vacuum’,Ga naar eind9 as a ‘vulgarized-economic fata morgana’.Ga naar eind10 But was it? The 19th century showed empirically the long distance which separates the laying of the basis of industrialization and the production of consumer goods. The establishment of heavy industries in Western Europe itself, the building of steamships, the construction of railways over the globe, were one long haul of investment, financed effectively by the ‘waiting’ of Europeans, their non-consuming of a rising national product, which was basically geared to increasing investments. To quote the famous passage from J.M. Keynes' Economic Consequences of the Peace: The railways of the world, which that age built as a monument to posterity, were, not less than the Pyramids of Egypt, the work of labour which was not free to consume in immediate enjoyment the full equivalent of its efforts. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 277]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
to defer, and to cultivate the pleasures of security and anticipation. Saving was for old age or for your children; but this was only in theory - the virtue of the cake was that it was never to be consumed, neither by you nor by your childeren after you.Ga naar eind11 In the country of Tugan Baranowsky itself, Marx' own disciples were to learn and to prove in the 20th century that investment is indeed for a considerable time independent (and actually preventive) of increased consumer demand. 2. The rise in consumer demand. - If investment could supply part of the effective demand of a rising national product, there was equally an increase in consumer demand. As the Revisionists were to recognize, the Marxian tenet of an absolute, or even of a relative, increase in the poverty of the masses under capitalism (Verelendung) did not actually take place in Western economies. In fact, workers' incomes have risen at least pari passu with the rise in national income generally. It is somewhat strange to believe with Lenin that such an increase was only possible through imperialist gains, and to hold at the same time that imperialism was necessary to get rid of the surplus products of the Western economy itself. 3. The fallacy of extra-capitalist demand. - As she over-exposed the contradictions of a capitalist economy, Rosa Luxemburg paid strangely little attention to the effects of her own solution: trade with non-capitalist buyers. It is clear from her analysis that she meant mutual exchange, not investments or cyclical effects. Even a child knew, she wrote, ‘that goods when they are exported, are not destroyed, but exchanged, and that from those non-capitalist areas and strata generally other goods are bought in their place which serve to provide the capitalist economy again with producer and consumer goods’.Ga naar eind12 Or, as she wrote in another passage: it was not necessary ‘to destroy a certain portion of surplus value, to chase it from the earth’, all was a matter ‘of realization, of the metamorphosis, hence of the “changed form” of surplus value’.Ga naar eind13 But if so, why did her dei ex machina, non-capitalist buyers and sellers, fundamentally alter the problem? If the capitalist economy was provided in return with consumer goods, from where then would suddenly spring the effective demand for them? It is no answer to say that non-capitalist products were different, or more attractive; the most characteristic quality of capitalism has proved to be its extraordinary potential to diversify products, to stimulate the desires of new consumers. Even many products of colonial economies were only discovered through Western invention. If, on the other hand, capitalists obtained producer goods in return for the goods which they themselves sold to non-capitalist buyers, what else, then, is this but an investment transaction, exactly as Tugan Baranowsky had described? | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 278]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The theory in the light of actual dataIn Table 1 figures are given of the percentage of colonial trade for each of the main imperialist powers between 1894 and 1934 with particular areas. From these figures it is quite clear, that throughout the heyday of imperialism, colonial powers traded far more with areas they did not control than with their own colonies. Tabel 1. Trade with colonies and self-governing territories of the main imperialist powers, as a share of their total foreign trade (1894-1934)
Data: Grover Clark, The Balance Sheets of Imperialism: Facts and Figures on Colonies, 1936 Also, they generally found little difficulty in selling to colonies dominated by another power. Conversely, non-colonial powers were rarely excluded from markets, whether in the imperialist mother countries, or in the colonies of the latter. Trade followed first of all not the flag, but effective demand. Most of the effective demand was increasingly concentrated, not in colonial territories, and certainly not in the more recently acquired territories which were the poorest of all, but in rival capitalist markets and in the large areas of the Americas and Australasia, to which European capital and European labour migrated. Britain consistently sold more goods to Germany than to India; its total trade with Germany was almost two-thirds of all its trade with the British dominions. Within the Empire, the self-governing dominions (which often raised tariffs against Britain) were far more effective markets than all | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 279]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
other colonies together. The trade of recent colonial powers, Italy, Germany, and Japan, with their own dependencies, was pitifully small. If foreign markets were indeed necessary for their massive expansion of industry, colonial rule was patently not.Ga naar eind14 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
2 Imperialism and the need for investment opportunitiesRosa Luxemburg had paid little attention to colonial investment (as against colonial trade) in her analysis. Before she wrote, J.A. Hobson (Imperialism, A Study, 1902), Otto Bauer (Die Nationalitätenfrage und die Sozialdemokratie, 1906), and Rudolf Hilferding (Das Finanzkapital, 1910) had given more attention to the supposed need of capitalism to find investment opportunities. As we saw earlier, investments were indeed a means to fill a possible gap in the effective demand within capitalist economies, and Hobson had stressed this fact. He began his analysis by pointing out the fantastic discrepancies between the cost of imperialism to the tax-payer and the actual profit to be derived from colonialism, summing up his conclusions as follows: First, the external trade of Great Britain bears a small and diminishing proportion to its internal industry and trade. Secondly, of the external trade, that with British possessions bears a diminishing proportion to that with foreign countries. Thirdly, of the trade with British possessions the tropical trade, and in particular the trade with the new tropical possessions, is the smallest, least progressive and most fluctuating in quantity, while it is the lowest in the character of the goods it embraces.Ga naar eind15 Nevertheless, Hobson said, imperialism created investment opportunities which were profitable to influential capitalist circles, and an imperative necessity for capitalism to maintain full employment. His theory was best set out in the following passage: An era of cut-throat competition, followed by a rapid process of amalgamation, has thrown an enormous quantity of wealth into the hands of a small number of captains of industry. No luxury of living to which this class could attain kept pace with its rise of income, and a process of automatic saving set in upon an unprecedented scale. The investments of these savings in other industries helped to bring these under the same concentrative forces. Thus a great increase of savings seeking profitable investment is synchronous with a stricter economy of the existing capital. No doubt the rapid growth of a population accustomed to a high and an always ascending standard of comfort, absorbs in the satisfaction of its wants a large quantity of new capital. But the actual rate of saving, conjoined with a more economical application of forms of existing capital, has ex- | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 280]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
ceeded considerably the rise of the national consumption of manufactures. The power of production has far outstripped the actual rate of consumption, and, contrary to the older economic theory, has been unable to force a corresponding increase of consumption by lowering prices.Ga naar eind16 As we shall see presently, Otto Bauer and Rudolf Hilferding based their theories of imperialism in the main on different grounds. Unlike Hobson or Rosa Luxemburg, Hilferding did not hold an under-consumptionist theory of capitalism; he agreed with Tugan Baranowsky that capitalism could theoretically expand indefinitely as long as capitalists continued to buy one another's product for the sake of further investment. But Bauer and Hilferding, too, attributed considerable influence to the need of surplus capital to find investment opportunities. Hilferding particularly stressed the declining rate of profit, caused by the increasing capital intensity of the production process (which diminishes the amount of surplus value produced per unit of constant capital). He furthermore believed that the concentration of ownership in trusts, would increase the amount of idle capital in search of investment. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Theoretical flawsWhatever its motives, it was argued that capital export was an imperative need for capitalism; without it, so the argument ran, total production was bound to be restricted to levels well below the effective productive potential of the capitalist economy.Ga naar eind17 Against this, it should be reiterated, in the first place, that consumption did not decline in the west, not even relatively, as Hobson and Hilferding, just as Rosa Luxemburg, still held to be true. In the second place, stating that capital was sent abroad in the heyday of imperialism is not the same thing as saying that it could not have been employed at home. The rates of profit on British foreign investments tended to be not at all, or only marginally, higher than those on home investments during the imperialist era.Ga naar eind18 If Hobson or Hilferding had maintained that not the fact but the lure of greater profits held out by investment bankers made capital move from the main capitalist countries to distant territories, they would probably have been correct. But then the actual returns greatly disappointed the investors. The export of capital was in that case not an economic necessity, but a psychological deception. It is an interesting commentary on the Zeitgeist that Marxist writers, imperial propagandists, and capitalist investors, were equally wrong in overestimating the profits to be obtained from colonial investments. In the third place, the complex mechanism of long-term capital movements is often misunderstood. Some authors have pointed to the supposed need of capitalist economies to dispose of their own surplus products by | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 281]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
foreign investments. This would ceteris paribus imply an active balance of trade on the part of capitalist nations, and a passive one on that of the underdeveloped areas. If true, this would imply that during the imperialist era more aggregate value was shipped to these latter areas than was drawn from them - a situation which could hardly be described as exploitation. Others have argued, on the contrary, that nations like Britain were essentially rentier nations. They have adduced in evidence the circumstance that Britain tended to have a passive trade balance during most of the 19th century. But in doing so, they have often confused the balance of trade with the balance of payments, and forgotten to take into account British invisible exports which allowed a continuous new flow of capital from Britain to outlying areas. There is some evidence that in the period after 1870 dividends from earlier investments and new foreign investments cancelled one another out, so that in fact little net transfer of goods and services occurred.Ga naar eind19 Profits, in other words, were in toto reinvested. This increased the indebtedness of non-European areas to Europe, but did not necessarily increase the economic burden on their economies. In so far as these investments and re-investments increased the productive capacity of the debtor nations, beyond that necessary to pay the increased interest, the economic advantage was theirs. This is, of course, even more true at the moment that borrowers defaulted in their public debts, or nationalized the assets of private foreign investors within their boundaries. Finally, it is rash to conclude that capital would not eventually have been invested at lower rates on the home market, if a surplus of capital had pressed for employment there. Nor is it enough to say, that the one-sided character of early industrial capitalism (textiles and steel!) prevented capitalism from finding markets in a satiated domestic economy. There may not have been a market for more railways, but there could have been for other steel products. It is even arguable that the availability of foreign investment markets postponed the differentiation of the European economies, which might otherwise have been forced at a much earlier stage of industrial development. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The theory in the light of actual dataMuch more important than to engage in speculations on what might have been is it to test the theory against the actual facts of foreign investment in the imperialist era. Even if it were granted that capital exports were a sine qua non for Western development, quod non, this still falls short of proving that capital exports were only possible through imperialism. Actually, the entire theory that ‘imperialism is the policy of forcefully creating opportunities for capital export’ is a classical example of a tautology. The definition is postulated. Then it is proved to one's satisfaction that capitalism needed capital- | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 282]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Figure 1. Geographical Distribution of British, French, and German Foreign Investments, 1913-1914
Source: E.W. Stanley, War and the Private Investor, 1936, p. 11 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 283]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
exports. As capital exports could only be effected through imperialism, capitalism inexorably produced imperialism. The entire argument is a non sequitur. It is a matter of historical record that the greater part of Western capital exports did not go to areas controlled by the imperialist powers. Figure 1 gives the geographical distribution of the investments of the three largest colonial powers in 1914, Britain, France and Germany. Table ii shows the foreign debts of the main debtor nations in 1929-1930, divided between dependent territories, self-governing British Dominions and independent states. Table iii shows the main capital importing nations, ranked according to their per capita indebtedness to foreign investors during the same years. Table 2. Foreign indebtedness, in billions of dollars, of the main debtor nations in 1929-1930
Source: E.W. Stanley, War and the Private Investor, 1936, p.13 Table 3. Total long-term investments from abroad per capita of population, 1929
Source: E.W. Staley, War and the Private Investor, 1936, p. 14 These tables establish beyond doubt that the main imperialist powers ex- | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 284]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
ported more capital to independent states than to their own colonies. Conversely, non-imperialist powers have found it perfectly easy to lend their monies abroad without resorting to any imperialist policies. The country with the highest per capita foreign investment was neutral Switzerland, to Lenin the one country destined to stay a capitalist museum once the world revolution would be successful. Again, whereas many capital-exporting countries showed little tendency towards imperialism, various capital-importing countries, such as Russia and Italy, did so. It is somewhat hard to believe that their imperialism was one of international capital pressure by proxy. Should one really stretch the alleged cosmopolitanism of capitalism so far, as to believe that the patently political investments of Czarist Russia near the Yalu River by the 1890's,Ga naar eind20 or the deliberate manufacturing of investment interests in Tripolis by ruling Italian circles in the early 1900's,Ga naar eind21 was the indirect outcome of the investment need of Dutch, or French, or Swiss capitalists? The proposition that capitalism needed imperialism to continue to expand is therefore disproved by the facts. It was not necessary for European capitalists to re-conquer the usa to force it to take their money: the money was as secure as circumstances permitted, the eagerness great. Nor did European investors have to resist the granting of self-government to British dominions, for fear that they would lose their investments or investment opportunities in those areas. Imperialism is not equal to capital investment abroad, unless one accepts a tautological definition. Nor should political control be equated with economic ‘control’ except by those who want to know the answer before they investigate the actual record in each particular circumstance. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
3 Imperialism as a regulator of the business cycleIt has been argued, incidentally, that imperalism was an important factor in the regulation of the business cycle of Western capitalism, during a period when other means to ensure a regular growth pattern of the capitalist economies were not readily available. Before the turn of the century, Tugan Baranowsky had laid considerable stress on the important function of overseas exports to renew an expansion of the capitalist economies after a depression. Almost sixty years later, A.K. Cairncross again found ‘plenty of evidence that it was foreign rather than home investment that pulled Britain out of most depressions before 1914’.Ga naar eind22 Zimmerman and Grumbach have given a detailed econometric analysis, purporting to show that between 1890 and 1910 imperialism provided a particularly happy expedient to compensate for a lack of effective demand at home during a depression by a rising demand abroad.Ga naar eind23 It has also been shown, in more structural terms, that there tends to be a peculiar relation between foreign trade and economic development according to a rather specific pattern. Foreign trade has generally | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 285]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
been small for stagnating, under-developed economies. As economies have expanded, foreign trade has tended to increase disproportionately, to decrease again relatively against the domestic sector as and when the economy has reached a certain level of maturity. Such theories make it possible to hold that imperialism, while not a perennial necessity of capitalist enterprise as Rosa Luxemburg and other Marxist authors held,Ga naar eind24 was yet a temporary requirement of capitalist development at a certain stage. This argument, too, is deficient as a general explanation of imperialism. In the first place, the same tautological fallacy often underlies these theories as it does the more absolute theories which hold that foreign investments were not a cyclical but a structural necessity. Typically, Zimmerman and Grumbach define Imperialism as ‘the foreign policy, which tries usually with the aid of military operations but sometimes with political intrigues only, to get control over under-developed countries to guarantee an outlet of merchandise or capital in those territories’. But in their more detailed econometric analysis, they do not differentiate between trade with colonies and trade with territories outside Europe and the United States generally. Nor do they analyse in detail the relative importance of self-governing territories as against colonial dependencies within the British Empire. It is difficult to find figures to prove or disprove what they themselves have only assumed, i.e., that colonies rather than extra-European economies in toto provided the cyclical regulator they seek to establish. Tables given by Werner Schlote about British trade in the imperialist era show little difference in the relative percentages of trade within the British Empire and that with other trading partners, in years of depression as against years of prosperity.Ga naar eind25 Also, is it so surprising to find that foreign investments increased in times of a slackening investment demand at home? Unlike the post World War i period when, according to the findings of Zimmerman and Grumbach, home and foreign investments rose and declined together, the period between 1890 and 1910 was one of long-term prosperity. Is it not rather logical that during steady employment foreign buyers and foreign borrowers had better chances when a temporary lull in the domestic economy made producers and investors more sensitive to the opportunities of foreign markets? If phrased differently: foreign investments were more popular in times of a decline in domestic investment demand than in periods when demand at home was high, is the conclusion quite so striking? If attention be paid to the long-term effects of capital investments for European economies at this time, it is likely that more attention should be given to the technical qualities of European industries. Was it really only imperialism which gave investment opportunities? Or railways? Why did European colonies not save Europe from the depression of the thirties? And why has the end of colonialism not thrown Europe into a long depression? As Schumpeter correctly observed in 1942, before the demise of colonialism: | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 286]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
‘We must not confuse geographical frontiers with economic ones’ ... ‘The conquest of the air may well be more important than the conquest of India was.’Ga naar eind26 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
4 Imperialism as the policy of finance capitalistsThe most important proponents of the theory that imperialism was essentially a consequence of attempts by rival capitalist trusts to conquer the world market, were Otto Bauer and Rudolf Hilferding. Cartels and monopolies, so they argued, were only possible behind protectionist walls. Monopolies allow capitalist interests to exploit the home-market. Both producer and banking interests which have a strong general influence on the economy, therefore do much to create cartels and monopolies. The increased monopoly price, however, curtails production, and increases cost per unit. To achieve the economies of large-scale production, capitalist manufacturers are quite willing to dump some of their products on foreign markets. Tariffs prevent competition of their own cheaply sold products on the home market. Offering cheap manufactures abroad will moreover help to oust competitors from foreign markets, and hence to extend the sway of monopoly.Ga naar eind27 The extension of the political area of a given monopoly-controlled economy may also enable particular trusts to dominate precious raw materials. Basically, then, imperialism is a conflict between cartel- and monopoly-dominated governments for the world market and for basic raw materials. The larger the economic area which is protected, the more powerful the position of the monopolies of particular countries. Hence, an unceasing drive for futher expansion: imperialism (or, as Shaw had it, Emporialism). | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Theoretical flaws of the argumentAlthough couched in economic terms, the basis of the argument is highly political. The unmentioned assumption is that capitalists have ultimate political power to force states to do their bidding. The history of Western capitalist development since the writings of those authors, has shown that both economic and political forces have successfully resisted the tendency towards an absolute concentration of power which Hilferding's concept of Finance Capital assumed. Traders have not become so dependent on industrial interests as he suggested they were becoming, nor industrial interests so much at the beck and call of banks as his theory of Finance Capitalism implied. Monopolies have been established, they have also been broken up. Practically all monopolies have been effectively challenged by producers of new products or independent producers of the same product. Nowhere has Hilferding's Generalkartell of a Gesamtkapitalist been realized in practice. Capitalist interests have continued to be rivals. Some have sought protection, others have combatted it. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 287]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The raw material argument, although prima facie more realistic, is also not acceptable. Cartels of raw material producers have often been coveted, they have as regularly failed, because of the disparity of the geographic and economic interests to be combined. The very assumption of a world cartel based on a particular product conflicts with Hilferding's assumption of Imperialism as a contest of rival trusts and imperialist states for exclusive political and economic domination. Generally, raw material producers have not made difficulties in selling goods indiscriminately to the highest bidder, whatever his national origin. Actually, therefore, the raw material scare was not an economic argument, but one emotionally, and unrealistically, political.Ga naar eind28 Enemy states, so it was held, should never be in a position to choke the lifelines of a particular economy. But, then, overseas possessions would only help those who had the military means to preserve them in times of war. Perhaps the loudest clamour for raw material control was heard in Germany. But Bismarck, for one, knew that German colonies would be of little help, as in case of war they could only be hostages to a British enemy. The limitations of this article, make it impossible to pursue further the very complicated issue whether protectionism is a necessary condition, or at least a powerful instrument, for rapid economic growth. On the one hand, the experience of a number of smaller states, oriented towards a large measure of free trade, would seem to militate against a too easy affirmative answer. On the other hand, the strongest argument of those who attribute colonial underdevelopment to the political control by European states is the affirmation that a lack of independence on their part prevented colonies from erecting protective barriers to nurse their own industries (as did the usa and some British dominions). In this context, one might note an interesting reversal of the protectionist argument. The Liberal economist, Lionel Robbins, argued in his The Economic Causes of War (1939) that the danger of protectionist policies by other colonial powers made British colonial conquest necessary. Not to ensure trade, but to prevent others from closing open doors, British colonial policy, he held, had been morally justified! | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The actual recordNot without justice, Hilferding's theory has often been called a typically German theory. The imperialist disposition of heavy industrial interests in Germany, the powerful influence of banks on industry, and the German historical economists' genuflexion for protection and supposedly necessary Raumwirtschaften have had few resemblances in other imperialist countries.Ga naar eind29 This influence had two consequences: it made the Austrian and German Marxist writers exaggerate the bellicose disposition of capitalists generally, | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 288]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
(whereas they in practice only thought of certain imperialist capitalist interests in Germany); and having proved capitalist causation to their own satisfaction, they came to underestimate the influence of other imperialist forces. Although disapproving of German imperialism, they were nevertheless led to take German imperialist complaints about ‘a place under the (colonial) sun’, the clamour for raw materials, and the militarist urge for a strong army and a newly built navy, as representative of conditions in capitalist states generally. Writing in the aftermath of the Boer War, they thought they had seen the undisguised face of capitalist imperialism, instead of an exceptional and controversial manifestation of British colonial policy. They projected the German situation on to Britain and France, even though the economic structure of industry and the banking world in those countries was dissimilar,Ga naar eind30 and their political outlook fundamentally different. Consequently, they failed to take note of the strong anti-imperialist tradition of important British capitalist interest. They neglected to draw their conclusions from the fact that French imperialism was not so much the product of the small-scale bourgeois investor in a country which would not be a mature capitalist economy for another sixty or seventy years, as of the revanchist and monarchist Right.Ga naar eind31 For similar reasons, they also failed to see that political interests in practice manipulated French foreign investments. No foreign loans were permitted on the French exchanges without government approval, and some, like the famous Russian Loans, were little but the buying of uncertain political favours with the aid of private savings, presently to be victimized on the altar of political expediency. A deductive explanation of imperialism from capitalist interests generally, therefore falls to the ground. Even so, it is still possible to hold that although capitalists as a group could not be proved to be imperialists par excellence, individual capitalists pushed governments into certain concrete imperialist adventures. Obviously, particular interests can always be found to have played a role in particular colonial adventures. (So could explorers, missionaries, anti-slavery humanitarians, etc.) In view of the fairly widespread anti-capitalist attitude of the Western intelligentsia, it is no wonder that proof of influence has often been constructed by historians to imply actual causation. Yet here again, renewed historical enquiry was to show differently. Eugene Staley has subjected all possible cases in which historians have held capitalist interests responsible for imperialist policies, to detailed scrutiny in his important study, War and the Private Investor (1936). His cases make interesting reading. He showed how time and again capitalist interests have been used by imperialist interests to manufacture pretexts for intervention. Of course, individual capitalists have often ridden the crest of imperialist waves. But like Cecil Rhodes, they have also often spent millions for no apparent financial, though much emotional, satisfaction. Rhodes' Chartered | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 289]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
British South African Company never paid a single dividend in all thirty-three years of its existence. Nevertheless, its shares continued to be popular on the London exchange. Georg von Siemens was to call Rhodes' invention of £ 1-shares ‘die Trägerin des neu-britischen Imperialismus’. No better example could be found of ‘capitalists’ sacrifice of money for none but emotional return, amongst practically all strata of British society. Staley's basic conclusion is unmistakable: ...Private investments seeking purely business advantages (i.e. unmotivated by political expansionism, balance of power strategy, military considerations or other reasons of state) have rarely of themselves brought great powers into serious political clashes. It is where an aura of political ambitions has attached to their investments, and especially where the investments have been pushed for political reasons from the start, that most of the dangerous investment frictions between great states have occurred... Private investments have usually, in actual practice, been subordinated by governments to factors of general political or military strategy, which have a more direct bearing on power. Thus it is that private investors have received strong, even outrageously exaggerated governmental backing where they have been tools and agents of power and prestige politics while other investors, whose projects seemed to run counter to the governmental line of political endeavour, have experienced official indifference or even active opposition.Ga naar eind32 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
5 The changing perspective on imperialismThe earliest and most effective criticism of the entire body of Marxian theories of imperialism was Schumpeter's Zur Soziologie der Imperialismen (1918-1919, translated into English under the inadequate title of Imperialism, 1951). Schumpeter's essay had the basic merit of assessing recent imperialist policies in the light of general history. He reviewed extensively past cases of expansionist empires, from the Egyptians and Assyrians onwards. Although he found certain economic interests to have played a role in some cases, he discovered as many or more in which this was not the case. Hence, Schumpeter defined imperialism as ‘the objectless disposition on the part of a state to unlimited expansion’. Schumpeter sought the roots of aggressiveness in particular social structures, differing from one expansionist policy to another. Instead of imperialism, in the singular, one should therefore speak of imperialisms, in the plural. Realistic analysis moreover showed that the main forces in 19th century expansionism were feudal remnants rather than capitalist interests, such as the nobility, the officer castes, nationalist memories of past military prowess, tariff policies from a mercantilist past, etc. To Schumpeter, capitalism was, on the contrary, essentially a rationalizing and individualizing force which diverted natural aggressive instincts to non-po- | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 290]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
litical fields like economic enterprise. In fact, imperialism should therefore be regarded as an atavistic phenomenon. Schumpeter's essay was dated. It partook of the fairly optimistic atmosphere of a pre-nazi era, and was still firmly, if negatively, tied to the debate about the capitalist causation of imperialism. In later life, Schumpeter was himself to reject the rosy implications of his own theory. In 1919 he still thought popular imperialism a logical impossibility. Later he came to associate himself with the theory about ‘social imperialism’ of another former Marxist, the Austrian Karl Renner.Ga naar eind33 If Schumpeter called in early history, contemporary history, too, was moving away from a close connection between capitalism and militarist expansionism. The rise of Nazi-Germany, of Fascist Italy, and of ultra-nationalist Japan made many observers aware of the unwarranted optimistic element in the theory that imperial aggression was simply the product of a passing social system, like capitalism, or particularly ‘evil’ men like capitalists. Some still tried to salvage something of the earlier theories by interpreting fascism as a particularly vile issue of a dying capitalism. They pointed to the fundamental anarchical nature of capitalism as responsible for the long drawn-out depression of the ‘thirties’. If it had not been for this basically chaotic feature of capitalism, and for the active anti-socialist support by individual capitalists, madmen like Hitler could never have risen to power by mobilizing the masses and showing that war preparation only could restore full employment. In themselves, such arguments already presupposed a host of sociological and psychological factors entering into the explanation. Since then, the later developments of Nazism in which capitalist interests were sacrificed to racial megalomania, did much to undermine this last stand of a capitalist theory of imperialism. At the same time, the New Deal and Keynesian economics restored the image of Western economies as being after all viable, self-sustaining social systems. Finally, the new expansionism of the ussr came to free capitalism from its exclusive responsibility for imperialist policies. Thus, three aspects of history have broken the specific link between capitalism and imperialism in the minds of many: (a) the more ready awareness of imperialist expansionism before the rise of capitalism, (b) the contemporary insight that capitalist interests could be anti-imperialist forces, and non-capitalist interests imperialist forces, and (c) the pervading fear for a future in which national interests rather than economic interests, ideology rather than capital exports, weapons more than trade monopolies, seem to endanger human existence. This reorientation cannot but fructify renewed enquiry into the actual causes of the establishment (as of the demise) of the colonial system.Ga naar eind34 Much more influence is now being attributed, for instance, to the mechanism of intra-European power politics at this period. We have come to see that the | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 291]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Free Trade Era was only a short and not even a complete pause in European expansionism. Between 1815 and 1870 a peculiar pattern of European politics made for a period of relatively little international conflict. At the same time the British Navy ruled supreme. It is now realized that the advent of steamships, and later the discovery of oil, changed the requirements of global strategy. We more readily appreciate the long-term effects of the opening of the Suez Canal in 1869, which gave Britain a new preoccupation in her traditional wish to safeguard the lifelines of the Empire, notably against Russian expansion. In 1870, also, the Franco-German War profoundly upset the international scene. Henceforth, a complicated and shifting system of international alliances was to determine world politics. It was this new internal European power game which made Bismarck somewhat reluctantly stake a claim for German colonies in 1884 and 1885. He thus provoked anew the scramble for colonies, not for gain, only to some extent for prestige, and to a large measure, at least on the British side, for fear that rival powers might enter the areas concerned. Perhaps the finest example of this new historiography is the study by Robinson and Gallagher. In their Africa and the Victorians: The Official Mind of Imperialism, they have carefully documented the actual motivations of British statesmen and officials during the imperialist epoch. They stress the basic role of India in the British Empire, as the military counterpart of the British Navy, an ‘Eastern barrack in the oriental seas’. As long as communications with India were safe, no British statesman was greatly interested in further imperialist exploits. England, Derby was to say, had enough black subjects already. Africa itself was little but an ‘empty’ space, by-passed on the way to India and the Far East. Typically, documents on Africa were filed for Egypt under Turkey, for East Africa under Bombay, for the rest of Africa under Anti-Slavery, except for Natal and the Cape which had their own files.Ga naar eind35 Robinson and Gallagher found therefore little trace of: new, sustained or compelling impulses towards African empire arising in British politics or business during the Eighteen eighties... The late-Victorians seem to have been no keener to rule and develop Africa than their fathers. The business man saw no greater future there, except in the South, the politician was as reluctant to expand and administer a tropical African empire as the mid-Victorians had been; and plainly Parliament was no more eager to pay for it. British opinion restrained rather than prompted ministers to act in Africa. Hence they had to rely on private companies of colonial governments to act for them. And again: West Africa seemed to offer better prospects of markets and raw materials than East Africa and the upper Nile; yet it was upon these poorer countries that the | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 292]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
British government concentrated its efforts. These regions of Africa which interested the British investor and merchant least, concerned ministers the most... Territorial claims... reached out far in advance of the expanding economy. Notions of pegging out colonial estates for posterity hardly entered into British calculations until the late Eighteen nineties, when it was almost too late to affect the outcome. Nor were ministers gulled by the romantic glories of ruling desert and bush. Imperialism in the wide sense of empire for empire's sake was not their motive. Their territorial claims were not made for the sake of African empire or commerce as such. They were little more than by-products of an enforced search for better security in the Mediterranean and the East. It was not the pomp and profits of governing Africa which moved the ruling elite, but the cold rules of national safety handed on from Pitt, Palmerston, and Disraeli...Ga naar eind36 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Section II
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 293]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
with a hasty reference to a continuing ‘economic imperialism’. The conventional argument, that imperialism reduced the non-European economies to servitude, in making them mere suppliers of raw materials and foodstuffs to their industrialized colonial masters, equally illustrates the confusion of economic and political factors. Political factors, like colonial domination, are hardly necessary to explain why the development of non-European economies took such a one-sided course until now. If the newly independent states continue to find themselves heavily dependent on European markets, this is because many of their export products were first developed under the impact of Western technical and managerial skills. If Western entrepreneurs concentrated in non-Western economies on raw materials and foodstuffs, this was not because Western capitalists as a class, or Western nations as a group, refused to let new industrial competitors arise in other areas of the world, but because individual capitalists found it generally unprofitable to start new industries in distant lands, until such time that external economies and an expansion of the internal market offered reasonable chances of economic profit. The argument that political power was used to prevent indigenous (or foreign) capital to engage in industrial projects in the colonies is more easily stated in debate, than concretely documented. The most one can say is that colonial economies, unlike Japan or the ussr for instance, lacked the positive lever of the state and the aid of protection. But it does not follow from this that colonial economies would have developed more quickly but for Western domination. Nor should it be affirmed too easily that non-industrialization is tantamount to under-development. It is an unfortunate though lasting effect of Liberal and Marxist thought that its industrial bias has often blinded statesmen to the fact that investments in agriculture could conceivably do more for an increase in economic growth than Fehlinvestierungen in industrial projects. It is not generally noted that countries like Canada, Australia, New Zealand, Argentine and Uruguay owed their initial growth to agricultural improvements and heavy capital imports, industrialization only coming in as an aftermath at a time when the domestic market had sufficiently expanded.Ga naar eind37 Conversely, the fargoing autonomy of political factors has often been lost sight of. Imperialism, as an all-embracing term apparently was sufficient explanation for the appearance of new powerful states on the world scene. The rise of Russia, Japan and the usa was shrugged of as yet other manifestations of the inevitability of ‘capitalist imperialism’; they were not assessed as basic shifts in the pattern of world politics. Differences in the political intentions and social systems of each of the world powers, in their foreign policies, or their geopolitical interests, have been inadequately understood. Too much importance is still being attached to economic policies as weapons of imperialist penetration, or anti-imperialist defence, while too little attention is paid to more basic social and political processes which may make or mar the independence of nations. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 294]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The influence on the WestThe first major consequence of the attribution of imperialism to capitalism was to sap the self-confidence of Western colonial powers. For decades, the morality of capitalism itself had been more than dubious. Hence it was fatal for the imperial idea to be tarred by the capitalist brush. The White Man's Burden was reduced to the nefarious money grabbing of sinister interests. Missionary activities came to be regarded as an ideological umbrella for economic exploitation. Guardianship came to be felt as an imposition, a sense of superiority gave way to a definite sense of guilt. Obviously, this did not only weaken the case in the mind of Europeans themselves, but also darkened the chances of success with which they might seek to defend their good intentions (if any) in the international community. The protest of colonial peoples, often in the name of Western ideals themselves, was one major factor in the demise of the colonial system. Lack of confidence among the colonial powers was another. The economic necessity (or desire) to reduce outlying commitments which the existing power felt unable to hold after the Second World War was a third. In addition, constant suspicion of ‘imperialist intentions’ joined the usa, other non-colonial countries in the West, the communist block, and a rapidly increasing number of emancipated former colonies, into one strong anti-imperialist front. Secondly, there is a curious inverse relationship between the sense of guilt and the type of economic relations which prevailed in past history between the European powers and the rest of the world. The predatory exploits of pirates of the 16th and 17th centuries, when a relatively poor Europe was superior to other civilizations in little but warfare, navigation, and arrogance, are still glorified in European history books as acts of great and good men. When, with the advent of industrialization and improved means of transport, plunder was to an increasing extent replaced by trade, this was considered to be of suspicious portent. But Western enterprise came to be regarded as basically perverse, when it came to invest in underdeveloped areas, even though this was technically accompanied by a transfer of substantive capital assets from the West to those areas. This paradox is not really difficult to understand, unless one continues to cling to a purely economic view of these relationships. Not the direction of the transfer of economic wealth, but the extent of European intervention in the social life of the communities they conquered and ruled, created the fundamental psychological tensions between colonial rulers and subjects. Hurt dignity cried out, rather than indignation about alleged exploitation. Thirdly, this also explains the short-circuit which is very noticeable in the respective appreciation of foreign aid. Overestimating the economic factor, many Westerners still fail to understand why such aid does not make them more popular. Have they not finally turned into benefactors instead of ex- | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 295]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
ploiters? Are they not showing moral rehabilitation for past errors? The fundamental reply to this is, that past errors were not first of all economic, they were social and psychological. They continue to have their effect, and are still daily committed. Finally, the capitalist explanation of imperialism was to weaken the political position of Europe itself, both internally and internationally. The easy belief that European wars were ‘wars of steel and gold’ weakened the solidarity between countries, as it did that between the various social groups of which European nations were composed. Hitler rose to power, partly because American isolationism and European appeasement were powerfully reinforced by the pacifist distaste for fighting another war for ‘capitalist interests’. Collective security crumbled, and national interest and patriotism were weakened by such political naïveté. Thus Hitler was given his chance to upset the world, and by his wager for the control of Europe, to give the control over Europe itself to non-European powers. Munich was the last conference in which European powers thought it possible to settle the fate of the world without the presence of either the usa or the ussr. Within a score of years, the usa and the ussr were to meet alone, to contest or settle the fate of Europe. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The impact on the Communist blockIf Lenin's Imperialism was little but a vulgarized amalgam of the earlier doctrines of Hobson, Hilferding, Bauer and Rosa Luxemburg, its political effects have been great. The adding together of capitalism and imperialism as causally linked phenomena, allowed Lenin and his followers to fashion the explosive formula that the struggle of the European proletariat (and its new Fatherland, the ussr) and that of national liberation movements, even if led by bourgeois nationalist leaders, is essentially a common one. Are not both the victims of capitalist exploitation? If capitalism can only prolong its life by colonial exploitation, does not the alliance of communists and colonial peoples form the most effective way of ending the tyranny of capitalism and imperialism both, holding promise of an international society, with neither classes nor clashes? For the same reason, it became possible to coin the doctrine of two kinds of war: reactionary, anti-historical wars (waged by capitalist, imperialist nations, to be resisted by peace-loving forces anywhere), and progessive, historical wars (waged by socialist and (ex)-colonies, for the sake of peace itself). The attribution of imperialism to capitalist causes has, at the same time, caused communist (as well as emerging) countries to misjudge developments in Western countries. It has caused them to underestimate the resilience of Western economies, to the extent that they have overestimated their reliance | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 296]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
on colonial empires. The continuing prosperity of the Western economies as well as the constant improvement of the living standards of Western labour, even though supposed surplus gains from imperialist domination are no longer forthcoming, somehow remained inexplicable. It has taken the communists long to realize that the revolutionary inclinations of Western workers are few and far between, in imperialist as much as in anti-imperialist days. | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
The impact on the new nationsBut most important has been the continuing effect of the Marxist theories on the outlook of the elites of the emerging countries. Its legacy has served to confuse the real issues of past, present and future development. In addition, it has affected the particular role which the new nations intend to play on the international political scene. The allegation that capitalist development of the European nations was basically parasitical, has been taken up eagerly. It allowed the leaders in the new states to minimize psychologically the widening gap between rich and poor nations. Did not imperialism make the rich countries richer, and the poor countries poorer than they previously were? Would the developed nations have reached their present prosperity but for the gratis support which the world was forced to tender them on the point of bayonets? Would the underdeveloped nations be in the sorry state they are in, if it had not been for colonialism? Such reasoning has made it possible to put forward the paradoxical and anachronistic claim that the presumably exploitative colonial powers ought to have developed the economies of their colonies as welfare governments, at a time when the ideal of the welfare state was not even held in the mother countries themselves. The exaggeration of the effect of political dependence on economic underdevelopment has, conversely, tended to heighten the expectation of what political independence could do for economic progress. Fundamental resistances in the social structure of the underdeveloped areas are inadequately taken into account. The gap between expectation and fulfilment in postindependence days increases the feeling of frustration in leaders and followers. A scapegoat is readily sought, and is often found in the continued ‘machinations of foreign capitalists’. Had not Marxist theory taught that foreign investments are inherently exploitative? Were countries really emancipated to see former foreign masters still in control of the ‘commanding heights’ of national economies of independent states? Such anti-capitalist attitudes tend to deprive the new nations of the assistance which continuing foreign investment might have given them in their development programmes. Ironically, the Marxist analysis seems on the way to being proved right post factum. If it could not be shown that in the imperial days trade (or capital) | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
[pagina 297]
| |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
always followed the flag, nor that the flag inevitably followed trade (or capital), the diagnosis seems to come true now, albeit in a reverse direction. The withdrawal of imperial flags makes capital often fly and trade flounder. Foreign assets, felt to be the illegal fruits of past exploitation, are readily nationalized.Ga naar eind38 Aid is demanded as of right. It is one of the strange consequences of the Marxist theories that it has made private capital (usually blamed for having no fatherland but that of profit) often more suspect in new nations than foreign assistance by one state to another (even with definite strings attached to it). Native capitalists may be implicated in such condemnatory attitudes. Their cosmopolitan ties may make them, by definition, potentially anti-national forces. This adds to the importance which many leaders in new states attach to economic development through the state, even though its administrative burden may already be excessive, and its determination of the priorities in development policies often far from effective (or efficient). Finally, anti-imperialism is often at the root of the particular choices which new nations make in the present struggle of East and West. Most have deliberately chosen a policy of non-alignment, which is more actively anti-Western, the greater its anti-‘imperialist’ ingredient. Communist agitation feeds on the supposed identity of Western policies and imperialism. Military expenditures demand a share of the national income rarely commensurate with any actual threat. As tensions mount at home, foreign policy is often a way to compensate or deflect frustration. Rarely, then, is the choice of particular foreign policies the result of a careful assessment of actual needs or threats. It has been the argument of this chapter that imperialist policies often hid behind quasi-rational economic arguments. Perhaps it is fitting that anti-imperialism should now at times try to cloak irrational economic views in quasi-rational political formulas. |
|